Full Employment for the Future

by David Stein    |   Issue 3 (2014), Theory

ABSTRACT     Who deserves what types of entitlements? On what grounds? In this moment of rampant and structural joblessness, there is an increasing critique of universities for their failure to create appropriate routes to employment for their graduates who are borrowing increasing sums of money to attend. Do these good students, who make, what President Obama has dubbed “good choices,” deserve jobs? If so, why only them? Or, with the extreme wealth of the U.S., should these good students, along with the bad, and everyone else, be entitled to a job or income? And what do employment rates for undergraduates have to do with the university anyway?

“School is not preparation for life—it is life, and it ought to be democracy.”

–Bayard Rustin1

Sora Han asks us to consider the role of lawsuits brought by imprisoned people that “lacked legal merit” and enabled the Prison Litigation Reform Act because they “failed to state a claim upon which relief can be granted.” Adjudications of those deserving of relief and their merit haunt the U.S. political life marked by histories of racist patriarchy.2 Such questions rely on ideological norms of calculation and assessment.  Who deserves what types of entitlements? On what grounds?  In this moment of rampant and structural joblessness, there is an increasing critique of universities for their failure to create appropriate routes to employment for their graduates who are borrowing increasing sums of money to attend. Do these good students, who make, what President Obama has dubbed “good choices,” deserve jobs?3  If so, why only them? Or, with the extreme wealth of the U.S., should these good students, along with the bad, and everyone else, be entitled to a job or income? And what do employment rates for undergraduates have to do with the university anyway?

Writing in a German daily newspaper in 1848, Marx confronted such questions by arguing that ruling regimes consistently attempt to mystify their modes of dominance in the  unpretentious term:  production costs.” Such costs, he argued, “are defrayed for the state by taxes and the taxes are raised by the  work of the nation. Thus in an  economic  sense it remains an enigma how any king can give anything to a nation… In all cases, the king can only give what is given to him. That is the position in an  economic sense.  It so happens, however, that  constitutional  kings arise exactly at those moments when people find the clue to this  economic secret.4 Part of building the undercommons of the university is first to acknowledge this “economic secret”: we, workers, make the university, on both sides of finance and production. Universities—public, private, and even for-profit ones like the University of Phoenix—are reliant on the work of government and thus the social wealth we produce.5 And secondly, an abundant challenge before us is to proliferate freedom practices within our workplaces and beyond. The university is one site for these actions, but, as Fred Moten and Stefano Harney have recently suggested, it doesn’t have any necessary relationship to the university. Rather the university happens to be their work place, and the location where they practice the urgent task of commoning.6 Commoning, in this sense, is the practice against enclosure: the insistent struggle for means of subsistence and survival, plentitude and freedom.7 For example, when formerly enslaved laundry workers in Atlanta clipped books onto their clotheslines to teach each other to read, while they “stole” time from their employer, they engaged in such practices.8 Commoning is the act of making the commons and the relations that undergird the places called “the commons.” Attention to how commoning practices were criminalized is what first directed Marx’s attention to the study of economics.9Likewise, practices of commoning also hold answers for anti-criminalization struggles.

Though reliant on the economic secret of taxation, many have recently argued against universities as commons, and instead maintained that colleges and universities are merely useful or “productive”10 for what they provide capital, whether as a coercive apparatus of a “mental discipline factory,”11 or a place for capital to externalize the costs of training workers in the skills needed for jobs in the market.12 But if one believes either of these types of utilitarian arguments for education—the latter more bourgeois than the former—then the cause of the crisis of daily subsistence and unemployment (which is a relatively recent phenomena for unemployed and under-employed college graduates whose skills and geography will not translate into jobs) then it is the universities that are seen as having failed to do their proper training;13  or worse, it is the students failing to appropriately assess which professions were in need of workers and choose an agenda of study accordingly; or the problem is the students own lack of bravery to take sufficient risk, as Bain Capital’s former managing director Edward Conard argued.14 Or perhaps, as President Obama has suggested, students lack the adequate metrics to evaluate “how well do…graduates [of a particular university] do in the workforce.”15

Such sentiments—that suggest the universities ‘lack the merit’  (in terms of job training and necessary science, technology, engineering, math [STEM] emphasis)  that would entitle them to adequate public funding—utilize inappropriate analyses, and instead a macroeconomic perspective is necessary to understand the role of unemployment in the contemporary political economy.16 Capital will not provide the necessary jobs for the current number of people, college graduates or not, unless it sees appropriate rates of profit in such an expenditure. As David Broderick, C.E.O. of U.S. Steel put it “U.S. Steel is in business to make profits, not to make steel.”17 Or as the founder of the Apollo Group, the parent company of the University of Phoenix put it: “This is a corporation…Coming here is not a rite of passage. We’re not trying to develop [students] or go in for that ‘expand their minds’ bullshit.”18 From the perspective of capital, use value means little; exchange value dominates; and high rates of unemployment are essential to maintaining working-class discipline and depressed wages.19 And as a result, for over fifty-five years, the Federal Reserve has worked arduously in order to ensure that the rate of inflation remains low, with the most marginalized workers bearing the weight of such policy choices that emphasize containing inflation over guaranteed jobs.20 Viewed from the perspective of the postwar Federal Reserve, few jobs are more important than the one played by unemployed people—helping to contain the inflation rate.21 These problems are not technical ones that can be solved with better evaluative metrics for universities; rather, they are  political  problems.

For colleges and universities to play their part in creating good jobs, one crucial thing should be the teaching of courses in the history of domestic workers. President Obama says he plans to “encourage more colleges to embrace innovative new ways to prepare our students for a 21st century economy.”22 Since the Bureau of Labor Statistics has predicted that the “health and social assistance sector” will be responsible for the bulk of the job growth through 2020, it seems important that these jobs should provide living wages and adequate benefits that all workers deserve.23 But domestic workers still struggle with gaining legal rights to organize unions to fight for such benefits.24 Like the problems of unemployment generally, this situation is not a result of personal failings of these workers or their supposed lack of “skills”; rather, the history of domestic workers show that their exclusion from the Fair Labor Standards Act had everything to do with racist and patriarchal Jim Crow political power in Congress. In 1938, the authoritarian experience of Jim Crow life ensured that only 4% of Black people could vote for the politicians who shaped the FLSA.25 This Jim Crow exclusion lives on with the continued marginalization of care workers from legal protections.26 And since such issues arose in the political sphere, they should be resolved in it. So, for colleges and universities to do their part in creating “good jobs” in the most rapidly growing area of the economy, they should teach this history and actively mobilize their constituencies on behalf of organizations like Domestic Workers United27.

From this analysis, we can see that the problem of wagelessness is centrally a political one, and that people who are without wages are central to the macroeconomic relations. As Marx suggested, “wages are…regulated by the expansion and contraction of the industrial reserve army.”28 But how was this group of wageless people created? And how could it have been otherwise? In the post-World War II era, the increasing automation of production, enabled by investments in constant capital and machinery (along with relatively inexpensive energy), pushed many people out of jobs and created conditions of labor surpluses—what Marx called the production of the “relative surplus population” or “the industrial reserve army.”29 While in recent history, college graduates have not been the ones who are redundant to capital as waged laborers, the great recession of the neoliberal era has changed this; people with a BA recently had unemployment and underemployment rates in the range of 4% and 8% respectively.30 The leading scholars of the rise of the prison industrial complex in the post-1960s moment such as Tony Platt and Ruth Wilson Gilmore suggest that the formal and informal control of this group of people is a chief responsibility of the police-prison relation.31  Perhaps then negating the production this surplus population can be an important grounding upon which abolitionist-reforms can be achieved.

This assessment of how wagenessness is produced and its centrality to political economy shows that the rhetoric deployed to legitimize budget cuts to universities and humanities education is disingenuous and diversionary. The production of surplus populations is crucial to the maintenance of a “healthy” economy with low rates of inflation and high rates of GDP. So, the critique of humanities education for inadequacies of job preparation misses the mark. Rather, historical analysis of the production of wagelessness, and those who attempted to alleviate such plagues, are better situated to understand how to address such crucial problems today. From this standpoint, we can make a powerful and uncompromising defense of Moten and Harney’s invocations to  study.  And in this sense, such studying is one difficult step from becoming an economic rejuvenation plan that could enable meaningful social reforms on a host of scales:  wages for students.

Starting at least with Reconstruction, the fight for a governmental guarantee to a job or income has a long legacy in Black freedom struggles.32 Few pursued such efforts with the fervor of Bayard Rustin, the great civil rights and socialist organizer most well known for his role coordinating the 1963 March on Washington for Jobs and Freedom. The March, which grew out of the organizing of the Negro American Labor Council, pushed for the full employment as its central demand. After the failure to achieve this as a victory for the March, Rustin continued to pursue such goals. But he also knew that since increased productive capacity was the problem creating conditions of wagelessness, the solution required a new way of envisioning waged work. In 1964 he explained that:

we have to redefine what work is now… we must recognize that the work of the young people is to develop their minds and skills for the benefit of society. There is no more sacred work. Therefore, I think that high school and college students who could not afford it should have not only their books paid for and their tuition paid—if necessary, get a salary in order to make it possible for them to consider their work school…as the machines take over various areas [of work and] the private sector of the economy is not capable of keeping people at work with dignity, then the public sector must come in and play a larger role.33

Such an analysis was prescient fifty years ago and remains so today. Indeed, it holds solutions to a number of critical problems confronting U.S. society.

Rustin wasn’t the only person to focus on this as a solution to problems of unemployment.  In 1975, a group of New England students published a pamphlet called, “Wages for Students” which utilized a feminist Marxist analysis to argue for the importance of the work of those without wages for capital.  This group criticized the notion that school is a “good investment” and that students should view themselves as a “little corporation.” “Going to school, being a student is work,” they explained. “This work is called schoolwork although it is not usually considered to really be work since we don’t receive any wages for doing it. This does not mean that schoolwork is not work, but rather that they have taught us to believe that only if you are paid do you really work.”34 Their analysis, formed through the crucible of the oil shocks and the destruction of the New Deal order, suggests a need for a return to full employment planning as a route to decouple jobs and education.

While the demand for a governmental guarantee to a job or income has been supported recently by everyone from the short-lived  Occupy Wall Street Demands Working Group  to  Bruce Springsteen, and persistently in the pages of  Jacobin Magazine, it will certainly take many strong movements on multiple fronts for it to become the dominant moral value that it was from the 1940s–70s.35 Some might suggest that this demand is a further integration into the capitalist wage relation; but as the theorists of wageless expropriation of value show, the unwaged work in homes and elsewhere is already integrated in to capitalist social relations.36 From this vantage point, to demand a wage for such work is to compel capital to internalize costs it has historically externalized.

But the demand for full employment should not be imposed on our present in an undialectical way. The extent to which full employment planning is the poetry of the past or the future is  determined  by how seriously one understands the problems of unwaged caring labor and environmental justice struggles (since behind every automated production line is the energy—and often fossil fuels—that power it).37 Full employment for the future is not about achieving higher rates of GDP or producing more widgets than any dumpster can hold. Rather, full employment for the future would plan for lower retirement ages, shorter work weeks, and socially useful and urgent labor such as elder care, childcare, teaching, education, conservation. It would confront centrally, the problem Harvey Swados identified in 1957, “the problem of work.”38

Indeed such ideas are historical as well and won’t need to be invented without previous precedent. There were a number of thinkers and activists within full employment movements who explored such concepts. Economists Leon and Mary Dublin Keyserling called for public jobs for conservation and creating new modes of electricity in the 1940s.39 A. Philip Randolph argued in front of the Los Angeles Central Labor Council in 1958 that as a response to automation, organized labor must “move vigorously for the establishment of the 4 hour day and 5 day week, social security coverage of domestic and agricultural workers and a minimum wage consistent with decency, comfort and health, education and recreation for all American families.”40 In the early 1960s people in eastern Kentucky formed the  Appalachian Committee for Full Employment  as a response to widespread poverty and unemployment created by the recent downturn in the coal industry, combined with increased  mechanization  of mining. They struggled intensely against mine operators, politicians, the police, and the leadership of the United Mine Workers while pursuing governmental guarantees to a job or income.41 Their plan for full employment included the creation of medical clinics, a special education center for children who needed supplemental attention and for adult education, day care centers, and rebuilding homes with adequate plumbing and sewers.42 In the 1970s and 80s, Coretta Scott King led the Full Employment Action Council (FEAC) as they pushed for things like solar paneling and weatherizing buildings to be part of a full employment strategy.43 FEAC worked with local groups like the Massachusetts Coalition for Full Employment to organize a solar-heating and weatherizing “work-in” with building trades officials to show what types work needed doing, and they began plans to coordinate with the Clamshell Alliance and Science for the People to show how full employment could be utilized for new energy sources.44 As King presciently argued, “full employment requires a major improvement in our educational system…it requires…major investment[s] in mass transit, [and] in energy.”45

Struggles for full employment are by no means revolutionary per se, nor should they be confused as such, but they are indissolubly tied to social reform and revolution in the way Rosa Luxemburg explored.46 Full employment serves to negate certain violences of proletarianization, and in that sense it enables greater proliferation of revolutionary strategy, but not in and of itself. Rather out of a new dialectical synthesis people emerge in a greater position of power; they become less desperate, less tied to a particular wage, less under the thumb of their sexist shift manager, and so forth. Then the question becomes, what new contradictions must be struggled over.

And what of government? How does such thinking compel us to consider what role governmental activity plays in the struggle to enlarge one governmental sector—public education—and eradicate another—the prison industrial complex? This is the tension of struggle around “the state.” As Moten and Harney suggest, “not only is [the state] not a monolith but it’s very, very thoroughly aerated. There are all kinds of little holes and tunnels and ditches and highways and byways through the state that are being produced and maintained constantly by the people who are also at the same time doing this labor that ends in the production of the state. So, what is it that these folks are producing?”47 And what happens when the public education and the relations of imprisonment are not isolated or directly opposed? What occurs when they bump up against each other? These are urgent questions that must be negotiated in actual political and social struggles with commoning practices helping to guide the way.

[This article was originally published at http://lateral.culturalstudiesassociation.org/issue3/theory/stein. A PDF the original version has been archived at https://archive.org/details/Lateral3.]

Notes

  1. Bayard Rustin, Who Speaks for the Negro?, Tape 3. Interview by Robert Penn Warren, 1964. http://whospeaks.library.vanderbilt.edu/interview/bayard-rustin.
  2. Linda Gordon,  Pitied But Not Entitled: Single Mothers and the History of Welfare, 1890-1935, (New York: Free Press, 1994). Margaret Weir, Ann Shola Orloff, and Theda Skocpol, eds.  The Politics of Social Policy in the United States. Studies from the Project on the Federal Social Role (Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press, 1988),  Michael B. Katz ed.  The “Underclass” Debate: Views from History (Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press, 1993).
  3. Strauss, Valerie. “Transcript: Obama’s Remarks on College Affordability Plan.”  The Washington Post, August 23, 2013. http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/answer-sheet/wp/2013/08/23/transcript-obamas-remarks-on-college-affordability-plan/.
  4. See: Karl Marx, “Reply of Frederick William IV to the Delegation of the Civic Militia,” in  The Collected Works of Marx and Engels, Volume 7, 476, 1848. http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1848/10/20.htm.
  5. For information on the reliance on of the University of Phoenix on governmental activity, see their own assessments: Apollo Group Inc.  10–K Annual Report 2012, 2012.  http://investors.apollo.edu/phoenix.zhtml?c=79624&p=irol-sec&seccat01.1_rs=11&seccat01.1_rc=10. On the history of enslaved people building and reproducing universities, see: Craig Steven Wilder, Ebony and Ivy: Race, Slavery, and the Troubled History of America’s Universities (New York: Bloomsbury Press, 2013).
  6. Fred Moten, and Stefano Harney,  The Undercommons: Fugitive Planning and Black Study” Minor Compositions (2013); 112–113.
  7. Peter Linebaugh,  Stop, Thief!: The Commons, Enclosures, and Resistance (Oakland, CA: PM Press, 2014), 2.
  8. Tera Hunter,  To “Joy My Freedom: Southern Black Women”s Lives and Labors After the Civil War (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998), 42.
  9. Peter Linebaugh, “Karl Marx, The Theft of Wood, and Working Class Composition: A Contribution to the Current Debate,”  Crime and Social Justice  no. 6 (Fall/ Winter 1976): 5–16.
  10. Marx suggested that “capitalist production is not merely the production of commodities, it is, by its very essence, the production of surplus-vale…to be a productive worker is therefore not a piece of luck, but a misfortune.” See: Marx, Karl.  Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1. Repr. London: Penguin Books in association with New Left Review, 1990. 644.
  11. The Wages for Students Students, “Wages for Students” (Branford, CT; Northampton, MA, 1975), 1.
  12. Christopher Newfield notes this trend, arguing: “By the late 1990s, leaders and citizens alike appeared to assume that society’s {and the University’s} core function was to stimulate economic growth.” See: Christopher Newfield, Christopher,  Unmaking the Public University: The Forty-year Assault on the Middle Class (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2008), 221.
  13. On “bourgeois utilitarian” social values, see: MARHO: The Radical Historians Organization, ed. “E.P. Thompson.” In Visions of History. New York: Pantheon Books, 1983, 22.
  14. For an example of this view, see: Edward Conard as rendered by Adam Davidson in his profile in  The New York Times:  “A central problem with the U.S. economy, he {Conard} told me {Davidson}, is finding a way to get more people to look for solutions despite these terrible odds of success. Conard’s solution is simple. Society benefits if the successful risk takers get a lot of money. For proof, he looks to the market. At a nearby table we saw three young people with plaid shirts and floppy hair. For all we know, they may have been plotting the next generation’s Twitter, but Conard felt sure they were merely lounging on the sidelines. ‘What are they doing, sitting here, having a coffee at 2:30?’ he asked. ‘I’m sure those guys are college-educated.’ Conard, who occasionally flashed a mean streak during our talks, started calling the group ‘art-history majors,’ his derisive term for pretty much anyone who was lucky enough to be born with the talent and opportunity to join the risk-taking, innovation-hunting mechanism but who chose instead a less competitive life.” Adam Davidson, “Romney’s Former Bain Partner Makes a Case for Inequality”  (The New York Times, May 1, 2012) http://www.nytimes.com/2012/05/06/magazine/romneys-former-bain-partner-makes-a-case-for-inequality.html?_r=2&pagewanted=all.
  15. Strauss, “Transcript: Obama’s Remarks on College Affordability Plan.”
  16. Tithi Bhattacharya, and Bill Mullen, “What’s the Matter with Indiana?” Jacobin: A Magazine of Culture and Polemic, (August 8, 2013)  http://jacobinmag.com/2013/08/whats-the-matter-with-indiana/.
  17. David McNally, Global Slump: The Economics and Politics of Crisis and Resistance (Oakland CA: PM Press, 2011). 70, Jack Metzgar, “Would Wage Concessions Help the Steel Industry?” Labor Research Review 1, no. 2 (1983): 26.
  18. Frank Donoghue,  The Last Professors: The Twilight of the Humanities in the Corporate University (New York: Fordham University Press, 2008), 97. Many thanks to Peggy Kamuf for noting this connection.
  19. The great economist Michal Kalecki noted this dynamic: “We have considered the political reasons for the opposition to the policy of creating employment by government spending. But even if this opposition were overcome—as it may well be under the pressure of the masses—the  maintenance  of full employment would cause social and political changes which would give a new impetus to the opposition of the business leaders. Indeed, under a regime of permanent full employment, the ‘sack’ would cease to play its role as a ‘disciplinary measure. The social position of the boss would be undermined, and the self-assurance and class-consciousness of the working class would grow. Strikes for wage increases and improvements in conditions of work would create political tension. It is true that profits would be higher under a regime of full employment than they are on the average under  laissez-faire, and even the rise in wage rates resulting from the stronger bargaining power of the workers is less likely to reduce profits than to increase prices, and thus adversely affects only the rentier interests. But ‘discipline in the factories’ and ‘political stability’ are more appreciated than profits by business leaders. Their class instinct tells them that lasting full employment is unsound from their point of view, and that unemployment is an integral part of the ‘normal’ capitalist system.” See: Michal Kalecki, “Political Aspects of Full Employment (1943),” in  The Last Phase in the Transformation of Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1972). 78.
  20. Gerald Epstein, and Juliet Schor, “The Federal Reserve-Treasury Accord and the Construction of the Post-War Monetary Regime in the United States.”  Social Concept  7, no. 1 (1995), Leo Panitch, and Sam Gindin,  The Making of Global Capitalism: The Political Economy of American Empire (London; New York: Verso, 2012), 87.
  21. For more on this argument, see my forthcoming dissertation, “Fearing Inflation, Inflating Fear: The End of Full Employment and the Rise of the Carceral State.”
  22. Strauss, “Transcript: Obama’s Remarks on College Affordability Plan.”
  23. Richard L. Henderson, “Industry Employment and Output Projections to 2020”  Monthly Labor Review, Employment Outlook: 2010–2020 (January 2012), 67–68.
  24. Sarah Bufkin, “Domestic Workers Bill Killed In California By Jerry Brown Veto,” Domestic Workers United, October 1, 2012. http://www.domesticworkersunited.org/index.php/en/pressroom/dwu-in-the-news/item/112-domestic-workers-bill-killed-in-california-by-jerry-brown-veto.
  25. Ira Katznelson, Fear Itself: The New Deal and the Origins of Our Time (New York: Liveright Publishing Corporation, 2013), 15.
  26. Alice Kessler-Harris,  In Pursuit of Equity: Women, Men, and the Quest for Economic Citizenship in 20th Century America (Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2001), 105–106.
  27. http://www.domesticworkersunited.org/index.php/en/.
  28. Karl Marx,  Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1 (Repr. London: Penguin Books, 1990), 790.
  29. This was not a decidedly post-war phenomena but a consistent dynamic in the struggle around the “machinery question” under capitalism. See: Marx,  Capital: Volume 1, 781–802.
  30. The Economic Roundtable.  Unemployment and Under-Employment: Los Angeles County, California and the United States (Los Angeles: The Economic Roundtable, September 2011), 6.
  31. See: Tony Platt, “Street Crime: A View From the Left,” Crime and Social Justice no. 9 (Spring-Summer 1978): 30, Ruth Wilson Gilmore,  Golden Gulag: Prisons, Surplus, Crisis, and Opposition in Globalizing California (University of California Press, 2007), 70–78, Geor Rusche, “Labor Market and Penal Sanction: Thoughts on Sociology and Criminal Justice,” in  Punishment and Penal Discipline: Essays on the Prison and the Prisoners’ Movement, edited by Tony Platt and Paul Takagi (Berkeley, CA: Crime and Social Justice Associates, 1980), 12.
  32. W.E.B. DuBois,  Black Reconstruction in America, 1860–1880 (New York: Free Press, 1998).
  33. Bayard Rustin, Who Speaks for the Negro?, Tape 1. Interview by Robert Penn Warren, 1964. http://whospeaks.library.vanderbilt.edu/interview/bayard-rustin.
  34. The Wages for Students Students. “Wages for Students.” (Branford, CT; Northampton, MA, 1975), 3.
  35. Doug Henwood, “OWS Demands Working Group: Jobs for All!,”  LBO News from Doug Henwood: Insta-punditry on Political Economy, accessed September 2, 2013.  http://lbo-news.com/2011/10/20/ows-demands-working-group-jobs-for-all/. Bruce Spingsteen, Bruce Springsteen’s State of the Union. Interview by Jon Stewart, March 29, 2012.  http://www.rollingstone.com/music/news/bruce-springsteens-state-of-the-union-20120329. Peter Frase, “Work It,”  Jacobin: A Magazine of Culture and Polemic (February 13, 2014) https://www.jacobinmag.com/2014/02/work-it/.
  36. See, for example, Selma James, “Wageless of the World (1975),” in  Sex, Race and Class—The perspective of Winning: A Selection of Writings 1952–2011 (Oakland, CA: PM  Press, 2012).
  37. Alyssa Battistoni, “Alive in the Sunshine,”  Jacobin: A Magazine of Culture and Polemic (2014), https://www.jacobinmag.com/2014/01/alive-in-the-sunshine/.
  38. Harvey Swados, “The Myth of the Happy Worker,” in  A Radical at Large: American Essays (London: Rupert Hart-Davis, 1968), 68.
  39. Leon H. Keyserling, “The American Economic Goal: A Practical Start Toward Postwar Full Employment,” 1944, Box 84. Leon H. Keyserling Papers, The Harry S. Truman Presidential Library, p. 14.
  40. A. Philip Randolph, “Statement to the Labor Conference on Human Rights, Los Angeles County Central Labor Council,” October 3, 1958. Box 40. A. Philip Randolph Papers, Library of Congress, Manuscript Division.
  41. Maggard, Charles (Buck) Maggard, Interview with Charles (Buck) Maggard. Interview by Thomas Kiffmeyer (November 29, 1990) War On Poverty Oral History Project. Appalachia Oral History Collection. http://nunncenter.org/OHMS-Viewer/viewer.php?cachefile=1991OH025_App297_Maggard_not_indexed.xml.
  42. Many thanks to Jon Free for making this research available to me. See: Appalachian Committee for Full Employment. “Community Organizing Program,” 1964. Box 1, Folder 3, Everette Tharp Collection, 1958–1976, 87M13. Special Collections, University of Kentucky Libraries, Lexington
  43. “Workers Construct Building with Solar Power Capabilities,” February 11, 1980. ILGWU. Justice photographs. 5780/102 Box 1, Folder 45. Kheel Center for Labor-Management Documentation and Archives, M.P. Catherwood Library, Cornell University.
  44. Massachusetts Coalition for Full Employment. “Meeting Minutes,” August 22, 1977. Julius Bernstein Papers, Box 7, Folder 22. Tamiment Library and Robert F. Wagner Labor Archives, New York University.
  45. Coretta Scott King, “Why We Still Can’t Wait,” 1980. United Federation of Teachers Records; WAG.022; Box 69, Folder 23; Tamiment Library/Robert F. Wagner Labor Archives, New York University.
  46. Rosa Luxemburg, “Social Reform or Revolution,” in  The Rosa Luxemburg Reader, edited by Peter Hudis and Kevin Anderson (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2004), 129.
  47. Moten and Harney,  The Undercommons, 142–145.

Author Information

David Stein

\David Stein is completing his PhD in American Studies and Ethnicity at the University of Southern California where he studies working-class history, African-American studies, policing and imprisonment, and the history of capitalism. His dissertation, “Fearing Inflation, Inflating Fears: The End of Full Employment and the Rise of the Carceral State,” focuses on Black freedom movements that sought to eradicate structural unemployment and examines contests over governmental responses to people who were disemployed due to automation and globalization from the 1930s-1980s. He wishes to acknowledge Shana Agid, Jon Free, Craig Gilmore, Ruth Wilson Gilmore, Sarah Haley, Sora Han, Gillian Harkins, Erica Meiners, Jake Peters, and Rebecca Popuch for their generative influence on his essay. Website: http://dornsife.usc.edu/cf/ase/student_display.cfm?Person_ID=1015681.\